Skip Maine state header navigation
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA
FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION
Devon Power LLC, et al.
) Docket Nos. ER03-563-030
EL04-102-000
MOTION FOR CLARIFICATION OR,
ALTERNATIVELY,
REQUEST FOR REHEARING OF MAINE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION
In accordance
with Rule 713 of the Rules of Practice and Procedure of the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission (“Commission”), 18 C.F.R. § 385.713 (2000), the Maine
Public Utilities Commission (“MPUC”), moves for clarification or, in the
alternative, rehearing of the Commission’s June 2, 2004 Order in the above
docket. Devon Power LLC, et al., 107
FERC ¶ 61,240 (2004)(“June 2 Order”). In that Order, the Commission deferred
LICAP in New England until January 1, 2006 and established hearing procedures
designed to produce an initial decision by a presiding judge on LICAP issues by
June 1, 2005. We seek clarification in
the following areas:
1. In the White Paper, the Commission articulated a central role for
states in resource adequacy issues. We
seek clarification as to whether the New England States and the regional state
committee (RSC)[1] will be
afforded input into this process other than simply participating as a litigant
in the hearings.
2. In its filing, ISO-NE recommended a regional dialogue to address a
number of fundamental capacity adequacy design issues. We seek clarification
that these are among those issues set for hearing and, if not, what other
forums may be available to address them.
3. How can we harmonize the Commission’s goal of long-term bilateral
contracts with the decisions of most New England states to move to retail
competition which typically result in relatively short- term contracts between
LSEs and customers or aggregations of customers? More specifically, can we fairly read the Commission’s order as
remaining open about whether the LICAP product must be a one- month product
purchased on or before the beginning of the first day of each month.
4. We seek clarification that the Commission’s prohibition against
allocation of CTRs to Maine generation that has not paid for transmission
upgrades will not preclude allocation of CTRs to Maine load, which has paid for
transmission upgrades.
1. In the White Paper, the
Commission articulated a central role for states in resource adequacy
issues. We seek clarification as to
whether the New England States and NESCOE will be afforded input into this
process other than simply participating as a litigant in the hearings.
Like many others, we have been frustrated that the process
of designing a reasonable method to ensure capacity adequacy in New England has
not been completed. The Commission’s
decision to place the issues for hearing, while an appropriate use of the
Commission's authority to move the matter to closure, nevertheless raises a
difficult problem. The MPUC, and the
other New England Commissions in general, have tried to work with the FERC in
achieving our mutual goals of an efficient wholesale (and, for the states at
least, retail) electricity market. If
the MPUC and other government entities in New England are confined to the role
of a conventional litigant, however, our
ability to find the solution reflecting our shared obligation to serve
the public interest (rather than the pecuniary interests that other litigants
must serve) is likely to be compromised.
The Commission has
recognized the special role of the states in resource adequacy:
Each region
with an RTO or ISO will determine how it will ensure that the region has
specific resources to meet customers’ needs.
The approach to and level of resource adequacy will be decided by the
states in the region drawing from a mix of generation, transmission, energy
efficiency, and demand response. It is
important to have a consistent approach throughout the region, which should be
developed by a regional state committee.
States may decide to ensure resource adequacy through state imposed
requirements on utilities within the region.
Or states may choose to have RTO’s or ISO’s operate capacity
markets. In any case, the choice on the
approach is made by the states within the region.[2]
One potential problem here is that NESCOE is not yet up and
running, although individual states can participate immediately. Whether or not NESCOE is fully operational,
however, the litigated nature of this proceeding raises the question of how the
states can provide their recommendation on these questions as envisioned in the
White Paper and in a manner consistent with FERC’s ex parte rules. One approach would be to allow the state
commissions or NESCOE to make a recommendation
prior to the evidentiary hearing
for the Commission and other parties to consider. Should the state commissions or NESCOE elect not to participate
as parties, the Commission might also consider their post-hearing
recommendations consistent with Rule 2201 (e)(v). There may be other alternatives. We ask that the Commission provide the parties and the ALJ
guidance on this question.
2. In its filing, ISO-NE
recommended a regional dialogue to address a number of fundamental capacity
adequacy design issues. We seek
clarification of whether such issues are among those set for hearing and, if
not, what other forums may be available to address them.
In its filing, ISO-NE noted that it had initiated a regional
dialogue to work toward a long-term solution to capacity adequacy issues. This dialogue, which the MPUC supported and
continues to support, was intended to consider a range of resource adequacy
issues which have not, as yet, been seriously considered, at least in New
England.
In its effort to meet the
Commission imposed March 1 filing deadline, ISO-NE asked, and the MPUC and
others agreed, to defer consideration of a number of basic structural issues in
order to allow the ISO to comply with the Commission’s timetable. That is the reason the ISO filed an interim
LICAP mechanism to comply with the Commission’s directive while also providing
a mechanism to consider a number of fundamental design issues. The MPUC believed this acceptable because we
expect that the region as a whole[3]
will have sufficient capacity for the next several years while a permanent
mechanism is developed and implemented.
ISO-NE outlined a number of
objectives which the regional dialogue was intended to address. This list included some fairly generic
design goals, e.g. the mechanism
should be simple and market based. But
the list also included a number of critical issues which do not appear to be
among the issues the Commission has set for hearing. The Maine PUC believes that the there are three ISO-NE objectives
which are both critical to the success of a capability mechanism and not clearly among the issues the Commission
has set for hearing:
A.
“The
mechanism should provide an adequate basis for financing new plant and
reconfiguring existing capacity.” March 1
ISO Compliance Filing at p. 51.This is critical for two reasons. First, the very essence of a capability
responsibility mechanism is its ability to encourage investment in new
resources as needed. Additional
investment in existing resources will then follow to the extent that such
investments are economic when compared to new resources. Second, and at least as important, we know
of two ways to protect customers from market power in capacity markets. The best approach is to structure the
capacity adequacy mechanism so that new entrants can effectively compete
against existing capacity. The
alternative, vastly inferior, is to develop a market in which only existing
capacity can compete effectively and then use administrative tools to mitigate
any market power abuses that may occur.
We believe that the capacity adequacy mechanism must allow for direct
competition between new and existing capacity resources.
B.
“The mechanism should recognize the lead
times required to develop new resources.” Id.
This goal is closely related to the prior goal and is important for the same
reasons.
C.
“The
rights and obligations of capacity resources should be clearly defined.” Id.
In our view, the basic goal of instituting an administratively determined
demand curve, such as the one the Commission apparently seeks here, is to
introduce some demand elasticity into the LICAP market. Elasticity would help alleviate the
‘bipolar’ nature of the existing ICAP market, which tends to trade at either
very low prices or the cap. However,
supply elasticity can also be infused into the market by more clearly defining
the rights and obligations of ICAP and non-ICAP resources. If there is a clear delineation of the
differences, there will presumably also be non-trivial cost differences to a
resource depending on whether the resource is providing the ICAP product. By extension, if there are cost differences,
resources will account for these differences in their offers to provide
ICAP. Simply put, this appears to be a
mechanism that would allow for an up-sloping (non-vertical) supply curve for
ICAP even in the short run. In fact, an
up-sloping supply curve can supplement, or perhaps even replace, an
administratively determined demand curve.
Each is, in principle, consistent with the other. Moreover, a supply curve of the sort we have
described could be determined directly by the market and avoid the litigation
that appears inevitable concerning the shape and magnitude of the demand curve
now before the Commission.
The MPUC believes these
issues need to be addressed, but they do not appear to be among the issues that
are explicitly set for hearing. One
variant on the conventional hearing
process the Commission might consider would be to invite the states and/or the
RSC to submit their recommendations on these issues to the judge in advance of the evidentiary
presentations made by other parties.
This option may be a more efficient way of addressing what are
predominantly policy rather than factual issues. It would provide the
Commission and the parties early guidance regarding the concerns of the state
regulatory bodies. Further, to the extent
state commissions or an RSC determine that there are no factual issues
warranting an evidentiary presentation and therefore choose not to participate as litigants in this
hearing, they could undertake the advisory role envisioned by FERC without
incurring the significant expenditures required to litigate a case at FERC and
could do so consistent with Commission Rule 2201 (e)(v). See
also State-Federal Regional RTO
Panels, Docket No. RT02-2-000, RTO Informational Filings, et al., 97 FERC ¶61,182 at 61,837(2001).[4]
3. How can we harmonize the
Commission’s goal of long-term bi-lateral contracts with the decisions of most
New England states to move to retail competition which typically result in
relatively short- term contracts between LSE’s and customers or aggregations of
customers?
The order suggests the Commission’s long-term expectation
for the capacity adequacy market:
The Commission stated in the
PJM Order that ideally, the market should encourage LSEs to engage in long-term
bilateral contracting and locational requirements for ICAP could promote such
contracting.[5]
It expresses similar views in response to ISO-NE’s query as
to who should be responsible for longer-term capacity procurement and long-term
reliability:
ISO-NE has sought guidance on the issue of what
entity should bear the responsibility for longer-term capacity procurement and
long-term reliability. The Commission
addressed a similar issue in the PJM Order.
As a general matter, the Commission believes that the market design of
the RTO or ISO should be structured to send appropriate price signals and thus
provide an incentive for load to procure capacity to meet their long-term
requirements. Through the regional
transmission planning process and the determination of the appropriate ICAP
requirements for LSEs, ISO-NE’s role is to establish the infrastructure levels
needed for the system to operate reliably. However, it is LSEs that have the
primary responsibility for longer-term capacity procurement and obtaining
sufficient supplies to ensure long-term reliability.[6]
The
Commission must bear in mind that, at least in New England, there has been a
widespread[7]
and largely successful attempt to institute retail, as well as wholesale,
competition. For example, Maine has
about 40% of its load served by competitive suppliers with the remaining load
served under standard offer contracts, which are awarded through a competitive
bidding process administered by the MPUC.
The standard offer contracts have been for terms of one to three years
and it is Maine’s understanding that most of the private contracts between
customers and LSEs are of similar duration.
Furthermore, Maine’s T&D utilities are not LSEs and their role in
standard offer procurement is purely ministerial.
This creates a significant problem in designing a long-term capacity adequacy mechanism based on long-term bilateral contracts between generators, particularly new generators, and LSEs. As a general matter, there are substantial financial risks in committing to finance new generation or significant upgrades to existing units without some level of contractual certainty about the value of the capacity once the investment is completed. This is particularly the case now when many of the firms that did make such investments are in bankruptcy or have turned the keys to their units over to their creditors. We believe that generators need either longer- term contracts or a substantial risk premium before they will be able to voluntarily invest in new capacity.
On
the other hand, LSEs would incur significant risk if they were to contract for
capacity beyond the term of their own contracts with customers. Given the relatively short-term nature of
those contracts, it is difficult to foresee what might lead them to enter into
bilateral contracts with generators which have terms sufficiently long to
provide help in attracting financing of new construction.
We
believe that this was the fundamental issue ISO-NE had in mind when asking the
Commission for guidance as to who should be responsible for long-term
reliability. Even if the Commission adheres to its view that RTO’s and ISO’s
should not take a direct role in contracting for capacity, the Commission should clearly articulate
what types of mechanisms may be available to deal with the retail market
problem we have outlined above.[8]
In
the absence of guidance from the Commission, we fear that the hearing process
will focus solely on short- term reliability goals and preclude consideration
of the need for some form of longer-term LICAP product. We encourage the Commission to provide
guidance.
4. We seek clarification that
CTRs may be allocated to Maine generators if they serve Maine load as LSEs.
The June 2 nd
Order seeks to allocate CTRs to load that pays for transmission upgrades. Under the TCA amendments approved by the
Commission in its Order of
December 18, 2003, [9]
Maine load pays for upgrades in congested areas of Southern New England. Thus, Maine load should be entitled to a CTR
allocation. The June 2nd
Order also states that Maine generators are not entitled to CTR allocation
unless they pay for transmission upgrades.
Finally, the Order envisions that one way to allocate the CTRs to load
is indirectly through load-serving entities (LSEs). In order to ensure that
Maine load is not unfairly precluded from CTR allocation even though it pays
for transmission upgrades, we seek clarification that to the extent Maine
generators (and, of course, indirectly the customers they serve in the retail
market) serve load in Maine as LSEs, they are entitled to CTR allocation.
The
issues we have raised in this motion revolve around one fulcrum. We believe that a viable capacity adequacy
mechanism must encourage healthy competition between new and existing
generation. If this competition is
correctly structured, we believe it can serve the twin goals of assuring
reliability and minimizing the likelihood of market power abuse.
We
also accept the Commission’s implicit recognition that a capacity market in
which both supply and demand are inelastic will often suffer from periods of
extreme disequilibrium, and see the Commission’s enthusiasm for a demand curve
as a response to that problem. However,
as we have indicated above, defining the LICAP product to achieve an up-sloping
supply curve could be similarly helpful and, if done correctly, could be accomplished
by the market itself, not an administrative determination as required by a
demand curve approach. We urge the
Commission not to foreclose consideration of this and other more effective
approaches should they emerge in the hearing or through the states' efforts to
provide input to the Commission. If the
Commission did not intend to foreclose this inquiry, MPUC requests
clarification to that effect. If, on
the other hand, such an inquiry was beyond the scope of the hearing FERC has
ordered, MPUC urges the Commission to grant rehearing and modify the scope of
its hearing for the reasons discussed above.
More
specifically, we ask that the Commission:
Respectfully submitted,
MAINE PUBLIC UTILITIES COMMISSION
/s/
Harvey L. Reiter
By:________________________________
Lisa
Fink Harvey
L. Reiter
State
of Maine John
E. McCaffrey
Public
Utilities Commission M.
Denyse Zosa
242
State Street Stinson
Morrison Hecker LLP
18
State House Station 1150
18th Street, NW, Suite 800
Augusta,
ME 04333-0018 Washington, DC 20036
Dated: July 1, 2004 Its
Attorneys
CERTIFICATE OF SERVICE
I hereby certify that I have this day served a copy of
the foregoing document by first class mail upon each party on the official
service list compiled by the Secretary in this proceeding.
Dated
at Washington, D.C., this 1st day of July, 2004.
[1] On June 25, 2004, the New England States Committee on Electricity, or NESCOE filed a petition for declaratory order in Docket No. EL04-112 informing the Commission of its formation as an RSC.
[2] White Paper, Wholesale Market Platform, April 28, 2003 at page 11.
[3] We accept the Commission’s determination that certain areas in New England, in particular Southwest Connecticut, have more immediate capability needs due to transmission system constraints.
[4] As the Commission there stated:
With respect to exempt off-the-record communications with non-party state agencies, the Commission takes this opportunity to clarify that it views the exempt status of such communication, and by analogy to the communications covered by the modification ordered herein, as permission to engage in such communications. In other words, by exempting them from the coverage of the ex parte rules, albeit subject to notice and disclosure, the Commission recognizes the importance of such communications to understanding better issues critical to the Federal and state governments.
Id.
[5] June 2 Order at page 18.
[6] Id. at page 30.
[7] The state of Vermont is the single exception in New England.
[8] Purely by way of illustration, one mechanism might be to have PUCs and/or local distribution companies play a greater role. Another might be to define the LICAP product as a commitment to provide capacity for a period of years, perhaps with a balancing market to allow LSEs to alter their portfolio of capacity in response to load shifts.
[9] The MPUC’s and other requests for rehearing of the Commission’s TCA Order of December 18, 2003, are still pending.